Andrés Velasco
Andrés Velasco, a former presidential
candidate and finance minister of Chile, is Professor of Professional
Practice in International Development at Columbia University's School of
International and Public Affairs. He has taught at Harvard University
and New York University, and is the author of num… read more
SANTIAGO
– Now that populists are coming to power in the West, a conflict over
the intellectual ownership of their approach is brewing. Writers like
John Judis claim that nineteenth-century Americans invented political populism, with its anti-elitist stance and inflammatory rhetoric. Argentines, who gave the world über-populist Juan Domingo Perón, or Brazilians, who brought us Getúlio Vargas, might beg to differ.
Yet there can be no disagreement that Latin Americans have been the longest and best practitioners of economic populism. In the twentieth century,
Perón and Vargas, plus Alan García in Perú (at least during his first
term), Daniel Ortega in Nicaragua and Salvador Allende in Chile, and
many others, engaged in trade protectionism, ran large budget deficits,
overheated their economies, allowed inflation to rise, and eventually
suffered currency crises. In recent years, Hugo Chávez and Nicolás
Maduro of Venezuela took these policies to new lows.
What should the rich world, now undergoing its own bout of economic populism, learn from Latin America’s experience?
Make no mistake:
judging by the track record of its establishment pundits, the rich world
needs some lessons. In Britain, Brexit opponents insisted that if
voters decided to leave the European Union, a recession, if not a
full-blown economic crisis, would be inevitable. After the referendum,
the pound depreciated some, but nothing much else happened. Today, the
British economy continues to grow.
In the United States,
academic economists repeatedly warned that Trump’s economic plans were
little short of lunacy, and in the aftermath of his shocking election
victory, some prophesied immediate economic catastrophe. Since then, the
stock market has reached record heights, commodity prices have
recovered, and forecasts of US economic growth keep rising.
Have the pundits been
smoking something? Or have Trump and pro-Brexit leader Nigel Farage
abrogated the principles of introductory macroeconomics?
Nothing of the sort. But to understand the effects of populist policies, one must first understand their logic. In a classic paper, Sebastian Edwards of UCLA and the late Rudiger Dornbusch of MIT define economic
populism as “an approach to economics that emphasizes growth and income
redistribution and deemphasizes the risks of inflation and deficit
finance, external constraints, and the reaction of economic agents to
aggressive nonmarket policies.” They add that populist approaches “do
ultimately fail,” not because conservative economics is better, but as
“the result of unsustainable policies.”
“Ultimately” can be a
very long time. Populist policies are called that because they are
popular. And they are popular because they work – at least for a while.
A sizeable fiscal
stimulus in a sluggish economy produces a pickup in growth and job
creation. If financial markets turn bullish (as they often do), the
exchange rate appreciates, quelling nascent inflationary pressures and
making it cheaper to import. And, as Argentine economist and Columbia
University professor Guillermo Calvo has long argued,
precisely because they are unsustainable, populist policies cause
people to shift spending from the uncertain future to the present, when
the going is good. This reinforces the expansionary impact of the
stimulus, which is particularly strong under fixed exchange rates. So,
eurozone countries: beware!
With consumption,
credit, and employment booming and asset prices sky-high, a warm and
fuzzy feeling of prosperity permeates society. Populist leaders feel
vindicated, and they are not shy about claiming credit. Their approval
rating can only go up – and it does.
Soon, teetotalers
begin to warn that debt is accumulating too quickly, credit quality is
deteriorating, inflationary pressures are incubating, and an overvalued
exchange rate is doing lasting harm to exporters. But the music is too
loud and the dancing too lively, so no one listens to the warnings.
How long can the
party go on? One thing we know from the Latin American episodes is that
the answer depends, first of all, on initial conditions. Most industrial
economies have grown little since the financial crisis. Deflation, not
inflation, has been the problem.
Yes, the unemployment
rate has dropped considerably in the US. But after so many shocks and
so much technological change over the last decade, there is considerable
uncertainty about how much unused capacity remains and where the
non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) lies. It could
well be that the likes of Trump find that they can stimulate the economy
for quite a while before obvious imbalances emerge.
The other thing we
have learned is that debt, both public and private, does become a
constraint. But when and how depends crucially on what kind of debt it
is. Today, advanced economies borrow in their own currencies at
near-zero (and sometimes negative) interest rates. Even if the starting
point is a high debt-to-GDP ratio, it can be a long time before growing
debt triggers an emergency. Just ask the Japanese.
What happens when
financial markets finally get cold feet and stop lending? Well, as the
Nobel laureate economist Paul Krugman was at pains to demonstrate in a recent paper,
an economy with flexible exchange rates and debt denominated in
domestic currency will expand, not contract, in response to a foreign
deleveraging shock. (Of course, Krugman was arguing for fiscal expansion
under a Democratic president, but the point still stands.) Not even
then do you get an immediate crisis.
In 1953, Perón sent a
message to Chilean president Carlos Ibáñez, a fellow army general. “My
dear friend: give the people, especially the workers, all that is
possible,” he wrote.
“There is nothing more elastic than the economy, which everyone fears
so much because no one understands it.” Trump, should he come to think
about it, might stumble to the same conclusion.
Anti-populists in the
US, the UK, and elsewhere must come to terms with the reality that bad
policies pay off, both economically and politically, long before they
become toxic. Yes, the excessive private and public debt, the loss of
export capacity, and the weakening of institutions harm the economy (and
the polity) – but only in the long run. If critics do not understand
that and act accordingly, populists will have as long (and destructive) a
run in the rich countries as they once had in Latin America.
No comments:
Post a Comment