Thursday, August 28, 2014

Hong Kong: A Case Study in Market Development

 by SUDHA R. SHENOY

 
Miss Shenoy, of India, is pursuing graduate studies in economics at the School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London.
Within the past twenty years Hong Kong has grown from a minor trading port into a center of manufactur­ing, with exports to some seventy nations round the world. Hong Kong seems to have found a formula for development that is not widely understood.
The number of industrial estab­lishments in Hong Kong rose from 947 in 1947 to 9,301 in 1967, the number of employees during that same period rising from 51,627 to 431,973.¹ Exports of manufactured goods in 1965 were 41/2 times the 1953 level. By all such tests of growth, Hong Kong compares most favorably with the United Nations’ target rate of 3.5 to 5 per cent a year. It may be added that Hong Kong has never experi­enced the chronic shortage of ex­change earnings supposed to typ­ify underdeveloped countries.
 
Cotton manufactures have re­mained the staple among export items, accounting for as much as two-thirds of the total in earlier years, but down now to about 55 per cent. Initially, simple knitted goods, piece goods, and yarn formed the major part of these ex­ports, but the industry has rapidly diversified to the manufacture of a large variety of clothing and the more highly finished textiles. Re­cent exports include woolen knit­wear, brocades, carpets, and lace. Textile machinery, originally manufactured just for local use, is now being produced for export as well.
Such items as firecrackers, Chi­nese foodstuffs, and bamboo man­ufactures once formed a major part of the export list. But by 1955, a wide range of consumer goods were being manufactured, includ­ing torches, nylon gloves, electric clocks, and enamelware. Current exports have moved further into the industrial range: plastics, cameras, transistor radios, air conditioners, water-heaters, light machinery (such as pumps and generators), and precision engi­neering products (e.g., watch parts and aircraft components) are now made in Hong Kong.
Hong Kong’s ship breaking in­dustry is the largest in the world. At first, the scrap was utilized in the local construction industry; but this, too, is now being ex­ported. With the development of the shipbuilding industry, yachts, and trawlers were exported, mainly to the United States. Tugs, lighters, and barges were built for Borneo, Kuwait, and Ceylon.
Hong Kong’s industrial develop­ment thus proceeded along classic lines, from the simpler consumer goods to the more sophisticated varieties; from light industrial products to the intermediate types. Hong Kong has never suffered from inability to import heavy in­dustrial goods, which supposedly hampers the development of many areas.3 Nor is there a Five- or a Ten-Year Plan or other such cen­tralized resource allocation in Hong Kong. Indeed, no govern­ment "planner" might have ex­pected Hong Kong to set an ex­ample of rapid development. It has few, if any, of the textbook pre­conditions for successful develop­ment.} The domestic market for many of its exports is narrow or nonexistent. It has no natural re­sources (with the exception of an excellent harbor), and no coal, oil, or other domestic fuel supply. The tillable area—13 per cent of a total of less than 400 square miles—is of poor quality. Hong Kong thus has to import virtually all its food, fuel, and raw materials. Even drinking water is pumped in from China.
No Tools for Planning
The Colony has other handicaps from a planner’s point of view: it lacks some of the most elementary government statistics and other guides for control over the econ­omy. Figures on registered indus­trial employment and daily wage-rates began to be collected in 1947. Trade figures were added the following year. A Retail Price Index was constructed in 1953 and an Index of Wage Rates the following year. But there are still no official national income estimates, or even an Index of Industrial Production. There are no official balance-of-­payment figures, no restrictions on trade and payments, no export du­ties, no central bank; banking reg­ulation is negligible. Consequently, the government simply has no basis for applying the various fis­cal, monetary, and other measures recommended in most modern text­books on public finance and devel­opment.
For most of the past twenty years, the highest income-tax rate was 121/2 per cent (currently 151/2 per cent); taxes on earnings and real property, and import duties on a narrow range of commodities (chiefly tobacco, wines, and drugs) are the main sources of revenue. Up to 1955, primary education (which is not compulsory), sub­sidized housing, basic medical services, and other "welfare" items accounted for slightly more than one-third of total government expenditure, with an equal pro­portion being spent on roads, water supply and other "econom­ic" services. By 1968, "welfare" expenditures had risen to two-thirds of the total, the total hav­ing increased from an average of HK $271 million in the years1948-55 to HK $1,800 million in 1968. (U.S. $1.00 = H.K. $6.00.) The increased provision of such services was made possible by ris­ing productivity.
Hong Kong has no minimum wage legislation, a negligible amount of labor legislation, and only a few very weak unions. Yet, take-home pay doubled between 1958 and 1967. The retail price index rose only 9 per cent in the interim, so this represented a sub­stantial increase in real earnings. Living standards rose significant­ly, as exemplified at a basic level by changes in diet. Per capita rice consumption fell, while its quality improved, and more meat and veg­etables were consumed. Imports of frozen meat rose from 26,000 tons in 1955 to 121,000 tons in 1965. Hong Kong thus combined rapid economic growth with a rise in living standards.
Quotas and Restrictions
Hong Kong’s development has proceeded entirely without gov­ernment-to-government "aid." In­deed, other governments have sought to curb their imports of goods manufactured in the Colony. The first quotas were imposed in 1954, by the governments of the U.S.A., Pakistan, and Thailand. The next year a number of South-East Asian governments followed suit, but Hong Kong manufacturers switched to markets in Africa and Latin America. In 1958, the U.K. government imposed limits on imports of textiles and clothing manufactured in Hong Kong; the U.S. government began limiting such imports in 1963.
The story behind these last re­strictions is revealing. It begins with the so-called agricultural price support policy of the U.S. government, which among other things, maintains the domestic price of U.S. cotton above the world level. The Department of Agriculture, then finding itself laden with "excess" supplies of cotton, added an export subsidy to offset the price support. Mean­while, imported textiles were be­ginning to replace U.S.-made tex­tiles in U.S. markets, as foreign manufacturers bought cotton (in­cluding American cotton) at world—not U.S.—prices, while their labor costs were well below the American level. American manu­facturers turned to Washington for protection against losses; and, in 1961, a "countervailing" import duty was imposed—to offset the export subsidy to offset the price support. Hong Kong textiles, how­ever, sold so well despite this ad­ditional burden that import quotas were placed in 1963. Hong Kong manufacturers have responded by improving the quality of their exports.
Other countries restricting Hong Kong imports by means of heavy duties, quotas, and the like in­clude Australia, Canada, France, Ghana, New Zealand, Nigeria, Norway, Rhodesia, Singapore, Switzerland, Tanzania, Uganda, and the West Indies.
Laissez-Faire
How did Hong Kong achieve all this? It has been suggested that the availability of capital and the presence of a large refugee popu­lation—obviously possessed of a certain amount of get-up-and-go are perhaps the two chief factors contributing to Hong Kong’s suc­cess.5 But those individuals who came as refugees to Hong Kong possessed their enterprising qual­ities even before they arrived; nor does a waterless rock off the Chi­nese coast offer the best prospects for investment. The difference lay in the economic environment, in the free markets created by pol­icy: "Almost complete laissez-faireism unleashed human potenti­alities, paralysed in other countries by elaborate control systems." The government made no attempt to impose or preserve any par­ticular resource allocation, but provided instead the stable legal, fiscal, and monetary framework that the market requires for opti­mal functioning. This use of the pricing system meant the full utilization of the empirical knowl­edge of ever-changing circum­stances, which can never be cen­tralized, but is only available scattered among individuals.? Re­source allocations were thus de­termined, via profit and loss, by international consumer preference.
Hong Kong’s economic growth was part of this general process. Investment in directions where returns were rapid and large meant that output and thus real incomes were raised rapidly; this, in turn, made higher saving and investment possible—but in con­tinuously more sophisticated types of machinery, which permitted not only further increases in produc­tion but also diversification of out­put. Resources were thus created where none existed before.
One fundamental point must be stressed: the course of Hong Kong’s development could scarcely have been predicted before it oc­curred, even on the basis of a detailed knowledge of the past growth of the now-developed na­tions. No one, in 1947, had any idea of what a developed Hong Kong might look like! It was only by the market process that this, in fact, became evident.
This logic is capable of wider application. In 1750, on the basis of the knowledge available then, it would hardly have been possible to "plan" in advance for the develop­ment of the North Atlantic region. Both North American and West­ern Europe were still relatively underdeveloped, and no one knew, in concrete terms, what shape any development might take! This il­lustrates the contradiction in what is termed "planned economic de­velopment": since we do not know what a developed Africa, Asia, and Latin America might look like, we are necessarily limited to planning for the reproduction of what has already been achieved, in the past, elsewhere! The market process, on the other hand, sets no such limitations; it is adapted to the realization of hitherto latent and unknown possibilities. Inasmuch as the underdeveloped nations represent, as it were, a vast realm of such unrealized po­tentialities, it is above all essen­tial in these areas to create the environment for a market econ­omy.8

No comments:

Post a Comment