Michael Spence
Michael Spence, a Nobel laureate in
economics, is Professor of Economics at NYU’s Stern School of Business,
Distinguished Visiting Fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations,
Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University, Academic
Board Chairman of the Asia Global Institute in Hong … read more
MILAN
– A knowledgeable friend in Milan recently asked me the following
question: “If an outside investor, say, from the United States, wanted
to invest a substantial sum in the Italian economy, what would you
advise?” I replied that, although there are many opportunities to invest
in companies and sectors, the overall investment environment is
complicated. I would recommend investing alongside a knowledgeable
domestic partner, who can navigate the system, and spot partly hidden
risks.
Of
course, the same advice applies to many other countries as well, such
as China, India, and Brazil. But the eurozone is increasingly turning
into a two-speed economic bloc, and the potential political
ramifications of this trend are amplifying investors’ concerns.
At
a recent meeting of high-level investment advisers, one of the
organizers asked everyone if they thought the euro would still exist in
five years. Only one person out of 200 thought that it would not – a
rather surprising collective assessment of the trending risks, given
Europe’s current economic situation.
Right
now, Italy’s real (inflation-adjusted) GDP is roughly at its 2001
level. Spain is doing better, but its real GDP is still around where it
was in 2008, just prior to the financial crisis. And Southern European
countries, including France, have experienced extremely weak recoveries
and stubbornly high unemployment – in excess of 10%, and much higher for
people younger than 30.
Sovereign
debt levels, meanwhile, have approached or exceeded 100% of GDP
(Italy’s is now at 135%), while both inflation and real growth – and
thus nominal growth – remain low. This lingering debt overhang is
limiting the ability to use fiscal measures to help restore robust
growth.
The
competitiveness of eurozone economies’ tradable sectors varies widely,
owing to divergences that emerged after the common currency was first
launched. While the euro’s recent weakening will blunt the impact of
some of these divergences, it will not eliminate them entirely. Germany
will continue to run large surpluses; and countries where the ratio of
unit labor costs to productivity is high will continue to generate
insufficient growth from trade.
Since
the 2008 financial crisis, the conventional wisdom has been that a
long, difficult recovery for eurozone economies will eventually lead to
strong growth. But this narrative is losing credibility. Rather than
slowly recovering, Europe seems to be trapped in a semi-permanent
low-growth equilibrium.
Eurozone
countries’ social policies have blunted the distributional impact of
job and income polarization fueled by globalization, automation, and
digital technologies. But these countries (and, to be fair, many others)
still must reckon with three consequential changes affecting the global
economy since around the year 2000.
First,
and closest to home, the euro was introduced without complementary
fiscal and regulatory unification. Second, China joined the World Trade
Organization, and became more thoroughly integrated into global markets.
And, third, digital technologies began to have an ever-larger impact on
economic structures, jobs, and global supply chains, which
significantly altered global employment patterns, and accelerated the
pace of routine-job loss.
Shortly
thereafter, between 2003 and 2006, Germany implemented far-reaching
reforms to improve structural flexibility and competitiveness. And, in
2005, the Multi-Fiber Arrangement lapsed. Without the MFA, which had
underpinned quotas for textile and apparel exports since 1974, global
textile manufacturing became heavily concentrated in China and,
surprisingly, Bangladesh. In 2005 alone, China doubled its textile and
apparel exports to the West. This development had a particularly adverse
effect on Europe’s poorer regions and less competitive developing
countries around the world.
These
changes created a growth-pattern imbalance across a wide range of
countries. As many countries took measures to address shortfalls in
aggregate demand, sovereign debt increased, and debt-fueled housing
bubbles expanded. These growth patterns were unsustainable, and when
they eventually broke down, underlying structural weaknesses were laid
bare.
Resistance
to the current system is now growing. The United Kingdom’s Brexit
referendum and Donald Trump’s election as US president both reflected
public discontent with the distributional aspects of recent growth
patterns. And rising support for populist, nationalist, and anti-euro
parties could pose a serious threat to Europe as well, not least in
large eurozone countries such as France and Italy.
Whether
or not these parties succeed at the ballot box in the immediate future,
their emergence should cast doubt on overly sanguine views about the
euro’s longevity. Anti-euro political forces are clearly making
electoral inroads, and they will continue to gain ground as long as
growth remains anemic and unemployment remains high. In the meantime,
the EU will most likely not pursue substantial policy or institutional
reforms in the near term, for fear that doing so could adversely affect
the outcome of consequential elections this year in the Netherlands,
France, Germany, and possibly Italy.
Of
course, an alternative view holds that Brexit, Trump’s election, and
the rise of populist and nationalist parties will serve as a wake-up
call, and spur Europe toward broader integration and growth-oriented
policies. This would require EU policymakers to abandon the view that
each country is solely responsible for getting its own house in order,
while upholding EU fiscal, financial, and regulatory commitments.
Upholding
EU rules is no longer practical, because the current system imposes too
many constraints and contains too few effective adjustment mechanisms.
To be sure, fiscal, structural, and political reforms are sorely needed;
but they will not be sufficient to solve Europe’s growth problem. The
bitter irony in all of this is that eurozone countries have enormous
growth potential across a wide variety of sectors. Far from being basket
cases, they simply need the system’s constraints to be loosened.
Will
Europe’s future resemble a slow-motion train wreck, or will a new
generation of younger leaders pivot toward deeper integration and
inclusive growth? It is hard to say, and I, for one, would not dismiss
either possibility.
One thing seems clear: the status quo
is unstable and cannot be sustained indefinitely. Absent a marked shift
in policies and economic trajectory, the political circuit breakers
will be tripped at some point, just as they have been in the US and the
UK.
No comments:
Post a Comment